Column: Consumer gut on inflation is wrong. That is a
problem for the Fed
Send a link to a friend
[October 21, 2021] By
Jamie McGeever
ORLANDO, Fla. (Reuters) - "Inflation
expectations" are probably two of the most important and scrutinized
words in financial market and central bank circles, playing, as they do,
a pivotal role in determining monetary policy decisions.
Unfortunately, they may also be two of the most meaningless.
Two papers published by Federal Reserve economists recently have poured
cold water on the notion that the inflation outlook according to
business, market, household, or economists' expectations is a
particularly reliable guide to actual outcomes.
This matters - hugely - because tempering and guiding the public's
inflation expectations is a key policy tool for any central bank with a
price stability mandate like the Fed. How policymakers respond to
changes in the perceived inflation outlook has a real impact on millions
of people's daily lives.
But according to a Cleveland Fed paper this week ( https://bit.ly/3nhPLrI
), the predictive relationship between a range of inflation expectations
measures and future inflation is, at best, patchy, and at worst,
virtually non-existent.
Consumers, in particular, have a poor record in predicting inflation a
year out, and financial markets aren't much better.
This follows a paper last month by Fed staffer Jeremy Rudd ( https://bit.ly/3G2Cg7J
), who went further, warning that belief in this supposed relationship
between expected and actual inflation "has no compelling theoretical or
empirical basis and could potentially result in serious policy errors".
Well-anchored expectations help ensure that the economy runs smoothly,
allowing businesses and consumers to make rational spending and
investment decisions. A benign environment like this in turn helps the
Fed meet its inflation targets, completing the virtuous circle.
But the Fed is in a quandary right now, and markets in a frenzy, as they
grapple with the strongest price pressures in years. Financial market
inflation expectations as measured by inflation swaps and breakeven
rates are the highest since 2014.
There is a growing view that the Fed will feel compelled to tighten
policy earlier and more aggressively than it would like to ensure
inflation remains transitory. Many emerging market central banks, most
notably Brazil's, are already well down this path, and those in
developed economies are getting twitchy too.
The clear risk is that if current inflation pressures do prove to be
"transitory", as Fed policymakers still claim, then raising rates could
slow economic activity, choke growth and maybe even tip the economy back
toward recession.
Can policymakers put their faith in these expectations, and if so, which
ones?
[to top of second column] |
Shoppers browse in a supermarket while wearing masks to help slow
the spread of coronavirus disease (COVID-19) in north St. Louis,
Missouri, U.S. April 4, 2020. REUTERS/Lawrence Bryant/File Photo
SPURIOUS LINKS
The Cleveland Fed paper analyzes inflation expectations from four main groups:
households (University of Michigan 1-year consumer surveys); professional
economists (Blue Chip Economic Indicators 1-year forecasts); businesses (Atlanta
Fed survey); and financial markets (Cleveland Fed model including nominal
Treasury yields, survey forecasts, inflation swaps data).
It finds that in some cases over the past decade the correlation between
expected and actual inflation has been negative, "suggesting a much more limited
ability of the expectations measures to predict one-year-ahead".
Professional economists have consistently had the best track record going back
to the 1980s and consumers the worst, while markets have been a "rather poor
predictor" of overall inflation since 2011.
Regarding the Atlanta Fed survey of firms' headline and core CPI forecasts, "our
results suggest that one is better off simply basing one's prediction on the
average of the inflation series", the paper's authors find.
To be fair, making predictions is difficult, especially about the future, so it
is understandable that people tend to look back in order to look forward.
Kit Juckes, head of FX strategy at Societe Generale in London, notes that
because expectations are a function of past inflation, they underprice what will
happen until inflation gets really high, then overprice it. By which point,
growth may already be heading south.
This can complicate policy-making. The chart below shows how U.S. consumers have
consistently over-estimated inflation over the past decade, although the
negative spread in recent months suggests that may be changing.
In his rather more incendiary paper last month, Fed economist Jeremy Rudd states
that the only basis for the view that expectations influence future inflation is
essentially because expectations are embedded into forecasting models at all.
He argues there is nothing more than circumstantial evidence for a link between
long-term inflation expectations and inflation's long-run trend, and "no
evidence at all" about what might be required to keep that trend in place.
But until something better fills that void, policymakers and financial markets
can only work with the tools they have.
"It is without doubt the biggest question of the day, and rather than a clear
idea of how it works, all we have is market pricing and forecasts," said
SocGen's Juckes.
(Editing by Gareth Jones)
[© 2021 Thomson Reuters. All rights
reserved.] Copyright 2021 Reuters. All rights reserved. This material may not be published,
broadcast, rewritten or redistributed.
Thompson Reuters is solely responsible for this content. |