Fed's Bullard, Evans, show two paths to the same policy rate
Send a link to a friend
[October 25, 2022] By
Howard Schneider
WASHINGTON (Reuters) - Charles Evans and
James Bullard are the U.S. Federal Reserve's longest-serving monetary
policymakers, a pair of PhD economists who've been at the center of
central bank debates through two acute crises and often approached the
job from markedly different perspectives.
Where Evans, president of the Chicago Fed, calls himself a "hopeless
romantic" about the longstanding economic concept known as the Phillips
Curve as a useful guide to policymaking, with its tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment, Bullard, head of the St. Louis Fed, dislikes
the idea, puts more weight on psychology and expectations, and has toyed
with different notions about what's really behind changes in the price
level.
But they've come up with roughly the same spot for at least an initial
stopping point if the economy performs as expected of around 4.6% that
they - at least for now - feel will lower inflation, and where they'd be
willing to hold policy steady barring any further inflation surprises.
Much of the Fed is in roughly the same place. As of September, 18 of 19
policymakers saw the policy rate at the end of 2023 ranging just a
quarter percentage point above or below the full group's median of 4.6%,
roughly the midpoint of a range of 4.5% to 4.75%. The Fed's current
policy rate is 1.5 points below that at 3.00% to 3.25% after a frantic
half year of rate increases from near zero back in March in an attempt
to quell the highest inflation in four decades.
In a window on the mechanics of Fed policymaking, Evans and Bullard in
separate interviews recently laid out how they were thinking
conceptually about that landing spot.
EVANS: "REAL" RATE OF 2%, WITH SOME HELP
Evans recently said his figure came from estimating a level of the
"real" - or inflation-adjusted - federal funds rate, that could lower
inflation without a dramatic rise in unemployment. He said a real rate
of around 2% seemed "in line with" restrictive Fed policies of the past
and held out the chance for a "soft" landing.
Though a gap between the fed funds rate and inflation of two percentage
points would be narrower than in previous tightening cycles - it stayed
around three percentage points for example in the years before the 2007
to 2009 recession - the aim is to lower inflation without the large rise
in joblessness seen in the past.
In the spirit of hitting a moving target, Evans said he looks at how
inflation is expected to evolve under appropriate policy. Stripped of
volatile food and energy components to give a better sense of underlying
trends, the "core" personal consumption expenditures price index should
end 2023 at around 3.1%, he feels.
[to top of second column] |
Federal Reserve Chairman Jerome Powell
(C) speaks with Chicago Fed President Charles Evans (L) and St Louis
Fed President James Bullard at a conference on monetary policy at
the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago in Chicago, Illinois, U.S., June
4, 2019. REUTERS/Ann Saphir
But in addition to the fed funds rate, Evans said he also accounts
for the tightening of financial conditions from the drawdown of the
Fed's balance sheet and adds "a little bit more for financial
volatility just in general around the world" - accommodations Fed
officials nod to in theory but which Evans recently put a number on.
Combining both "quantitative tightening" and the impact of global
volatility, he said, is the equivalent of about half a percentage
point on the federal funds rate.
Bottom line: 3.1% inflation next year plus a 2% target for the
"real" rate would ostensibly mean the Fed needs to hike rates to
5.1%. Accounting for the effect of those other forces lowers the
figure to 4.6%.
BULLARD: A "GENEROUS" TAYLOR RULE
In the early 1990s Stanford University economics professor John
Taylor derived what has become a touchstone guide for central
bankers, the Taylor Rule. It requires some difficult estimation of
such things as the underlying "neutral" rate of interest - the rate
that is neither restrictive nor accommodative to growth - and the
gap between actual and potential economic output. But the basic
formula essentially relies on the distance of inflation from a
central bank's price target to recommend a policy rate.
There are many variations, of varying complexity. Bullard has one he
has referred to recently as both "generous" because it requires a
less harsh adjustment of interest rates than a more traditional
Taylor rule would recommend - some versions suggest a federal funds
rate already near 8% - and "minimalist" in paring back the number
and complexity of any adjustments.
For example he uses an inflation calculation from the Dallas Fed
that relies on a "trimmed mean," tossing out the fastest and slowing
moving prices rather than automatically stripping out food and
energy as the most volatile. That price index as of August was
rising at a 4.7% annual rate, a bit less than the 4.9% rate of the
"core" personal consumption expenditures index.
Bullard said recently he has updated his calculations, which he
presented earlier in the year when inflation was lower, and "you
make the most generous assumptions, you get to four-and-a-half or
4.75" on the federal funds rate.
If the target rate needs to move higher, he said, "it will be
because inflation doesn't come down the way we're hoping."
(Reporting by Howard Schneider; Editing by Dan Burns and Andrea
Ricci)
[© 2022 Thomson Reuters. All rights
reserved.]
This material may not be published,
broadcast, rewritten or redistributed.
Thompson Reuters is solely responsible for this content. |