The mouse that roared: New Zealand and the world's 2% inflation target
Send a link to a friend
[January 30, 2023] By
Lucy Craymer
WELLINGTON, New Zealand (Reuters) - More than 30 years ago, some
relatively youthful central bank and Treasury economists in New Zealand
were grappling with how to bring two decades of double-digit inflation
under control in an economy less than 1% the size of its U.S.
counterpart.
What if, they asked, they just told everyone the rate should be much
lower - say roughly 2% - and then aim for that?
"It was a bit of a shock to everyone, I think," said Roger Douglas, the
Labour Party finance minister at the time who worked with the Treasury
and Reserve Bank of New Zealand (RBNZ) to pioneer the policy. "I just
announced it was gonna be 2%, and it sort of stuck."
Like that, inflation targeting was born.
Since it's arrival in 1990, the 2% inflation target phenomenon has
sailed from Wellington around the globe to become the accepted norm
among central banks, large and small, for grounding public expectations
for what inflation ought to be. But the price spikes spawned by the
COVID-19 pandemic are set to test their devotion to it in the months
ahead as inflation looks set to remain stubbornly above 2% for some
time.
As some observers question whether that level remains valid today - in
most cases debating if it should be raised to blunt the blows to growth
and employment from the high interest rates being employed by central
banks in order to achieve it - the inflation-targeting pioneers in New
Zealand are standing by it.
In fact, Arthur Grimes, a former chief economist and senior official at
the RBNZ who was seen as one of the key architects of the policy, would
like the target to include a lower range.
"Zero's the obvious sort of place to head for - it is basically saying,
on average, prices in 10 years time should be roughly the same as prices
now. Why would you want anything different?" he said.
'MOST DESPISED MAN'
When New Zealand became the first country to mandate inflation
targeting, the upper limit was 2% and the lower one just 0%. At the
time, inflation was running at 7.6% but had tracked above 10% on average
between 1970 and 1990, and few people thought the target was realistic.
There "were some pretty vicious internal debates, not everyone I think
was particularly convinced that we should be aiming for something as low
we were," said Michael Reddell, a former RBNZ economist, who at the time
headed the economics department's monetary policy section.
"It wasn't the most scientific process in the entire world ... we had
limited resource. Nobody had done this before us," he added.
The adoption of the inflation target was followed by aggressive monetary
tightening, with 90-day rates climbing to 15% in 1990. A year later,
inflation had fallen to 2% and New Zealanders' inflation expectations
adjusted quickly to the new paradigm.
[to top of second column] |
Two people walk towards the entrance of
the Reserve Bank of New Zealand located in Wellington, New Zealand,
on March 22, 2016. REUTERS/Rebecca Howard/File Photo
But there were severe short-term costs for businesses and workers,
with the economy stagnating between 1989 and 1994 and the
unemployment rate rising into double-digit figures.
Since that time, the target has been shifted twice, initially to a
range of 0% to 3% and then in 2002 to the 1%-3% range.
The decision - and the resulting policy - was driven largely by
politics.
Governments had engaged in spending sprees to win votes at the
expense of inflation. Douglas, the former finance minister, asked
the central bank and Treasury to pioneer the policy to prevent that
from happening again.
Initially there was debate about whether interest rates or money
supply should be the target, but it was decided it was better to
target the ultimate goal: inflation.
"They did all the hard work and I just got all the glory and the
title of being the most despised man in New Zealand," Douglas said.
IN THE SPOTLIGHT
But to New Zealanders used to high inflation, a 2% rate seemed
unbelievable. Don Brash, then the RBNZ governor and later the leader
of the opposition National Party, said he held grueling meetings
with everyone from news organizations to grassroots bodies to get
them on board.
New Zealand faced rising unemployment, with wages failing to keep up
with the cost of living. Reuters reported in 1994 that 13 protesters
were dragged from the foyer of the RBNZ in Wellington and arrested
after demanding the central bank let inflation rise.
"The conclusion from our history about that, is that if you don't
want to damage the real economy don't let inflation get away in the
first place. Because the path back to low inflation, from embedded
inflation always involves output losses," said Graham Scott, who was
the secretary of the Treasury from 1986 to 1993.
After the changes were introduced, New Zealand found itself under a
spotlight. It attracted better economic event speakers, and the
architects of the policy were invited to major gatherings including
the U.S. Federal Reserve's annual symposium in Jackson Hole,
Wyoming. Other central bankers were keen to understand what had
happened.
"'How did we do it?' became the bigger question than 'what we did,"
Douglas said. "I mean, most people didn't really argue with what we
were doing but they wondered how the heck we managed to get away
with it."
(Reporting by Lucy Craymer; Editing by Dan Burns and Paul Simao)
[© 2023 Thomson Reuters. All rights
reserved.]
This material may not be published,
broadcast, rewritten or redistributed.
Thompson Reuters is solely responsible for this content. |