Ex-Fed chief Bernanke says labor costs becoming more prominent in
inflation
Send a link to a friend
[May 23, 2023] By
Howard Schneider
WASHINGTON (Reuters) - A tight U.S. job market and rising wages are
beginning to have more of an impact on inflation and could embed faster
rising prices if the demand for workers is not brought into better
balance with the labor force, new research from an ex-Federal Reserve
chief and a former top International Monetary Fund economist has
concluded.
Ben Bernanke, who led the U.S. central bank from 2006-2014, and Olivier
Blanchard, the IMF's chief economist from 2008 to 2015, said the
inflation surge starting in 2021 was largely stoked by energy markets
and shortages of automobiles and other durable goods.
"However, over time a very tight labor market has begun to exert
increasing pressure on inflation ... That share is likely to grow and
will not subside on its own," they wrote in a paper released on Tuesday
by the Washington-based Brookings Institution. "The portion of inflation
which traces its origin to overheating of labor markets can only be
reversed by policy actions that bring labor demand and supply into
better balance."
The U.S. central bank has raised interest rates aggressively since March
of 2022 to try to slow the economy and reduce the overall demand for
goods and services. While policymakers are expected, for now, to hold
off on another rate increase at their June 13-14 policy meeting, they
have remained noncommittal as they await upcoming inflation and jobs
data.
The paper adds a new set of arguments, from two influential economists
who witnessed inflation's broad retreat during their policymaking terms,
to one of the Fed's central debates: what role a looser job market and
slower wage growth will need to play in any continued lowering of
inflation from levels that remain high and are only slowly improving.
LABOR MARKET SLACK
Some Fed economists and policymakers feel a point of steady
"disinflation" may be close, and hinges only on families and businesses
spending final doses of pandemic-era cash. Others, most notably Chicago
Fed President Austan Goolsbee, have argued that wage gains say little
about future price increases, but largely reflect past price hikes.
Atlanta Fed economists have cast it differently still, saying that after
COVID-19 pandemic years in which businesses saw outsized profits, there
is room for wages to grow through a decline in business margins rather
than a rise in prices.
In a joint appearance with Bernanke at a U.S. central bank research
conference last Friday, Fed Chair Jerome Powell seemed to have settled
in a place similar to the former Fed leader, saying that much of the
work left to be done in lowering inflation will have to come from a job
market still sustaining a 3.4% unemployment rate, abnormally high
numbers of vacancies, and wage gains outpacing the rate of price
increases.
"I don't think labor market slack was a particularly important feature
of inflation when it first spiked in spring of 2021," Powell said. "By
contrast, I do think that labor market slack is likely to be an
increasingly important factor in inflation going forward," reiterating
his observation that price increases are proving most stubborn in
service industries where "labor costs are a high proportion of total
costs."
[to top of second column] |
Nobel laureate in Economic Sciences Ben
S. Bernanke speaks during the Nobel Prize Banquet at the Town Hall
in Stockholm, Sweden December 10, 2022. TT News Agency/Jonas
Ekstromer via REUTERS
A Fed intent on producing weaker hiring and slower wage growth
would, at least in the past, imply rising joblessness. Indeed,
policymakers expect the unemployment rate to increase as their fight
against inflation continues.
How fast and by how much remains a contested point: Some outside
economists have estimated unemployment rates as high as 6% or 7%
will be necessary, while Fed policymakers remain hopeful of a more
modest dislocation.
Bernanke and Blanchard did not take an explicit stand on that issue,
but said it may still be possible for the labor market to ease
largely through a drop in the number of job openings rather than a
rise in joblessness.
INFLATION EXPECTATIONS
Their study, however, points to some of the risks Fed officials may
face as they decide whether to be patient in allowing time for
inflation to slow, or use further rate increases to force a faster
adjustment in an effort to ensure high inflation does not become
embedded.
Bernanke and Blanchard estimate that inflation could return to the
Fed's 2% annual target if over the next two years their preferred
measure of labor market slack - the number of job openings for each
unemployed job seeker - falls below 1 to around 0.8, meaning more
unemployed workers are competing for jobs than there are open
positions.
If over that time the ratio falls only to the pre-pandemic rate of
around 1.2, by contrast, inflation as measured by the Consumer Price
Index would fall to around 2.7% - still high, but "within striking
distance" of the Fed's 2% target, the authors said, given the
differences between the CPI and the Personal Consumption
Expenditures Price Index the Fed prefers.
But "allowing (the ratio) to remain near current levels does not
bring inflation down in our projections. Indeed, because an extended
period of inflation raises long-term inflation expectations, it
leads to slowly increasing inflation," they wrote.
The current ratio is 1.6, down from a peak of around 2 last year.
"The portion of inflation which traces its origin to overheating of
labor markets can only be reversed by policy actions that bring
labor demand and supply into better balance," Bernanke and Blanchard
concluded. "Labor market balance should ultimately be the primary
concern for central banks attempting to maintain price stability."
(Reporting by Howard Schneider; Editing by Dan Burns and Paul Simao)
[© 2023 Thomson Reuters. All rights
reserved.]
This material may not be published,
broadcast, rewritten or redistributed.
Thompson Reuters is solely responsible for this content.
|